Open Access
How to translate text using browser tools
1 February 2016 Community Water Governance on Mount Kenya: An Assessment Based on Ostrom’s Design Principles of Natural Resource Management
Jampel Dell’Angelo, Paul F. McCord, Drew Gower, Stefan Carpenter, Kelly K. Caylor, Tom P. Evans
Author Affiliations +
Abstract

Kenyan river basin governance underwent a pioneering reform in the Water Act of 2002, which established new community water-management institutions. This article focuses on community water projects in the Likii Water Resource Users Association in the Upper Ewaso Ng’iro River basin on Mount Kenya, and the extent to which their features are consistent with Ostrom’s design principles of natural resource management. Although the projects have developed solid institutional structures, pressures such as hydroclimatic change, population growth, and water inequality challenge their ability to manage their water resources. Institutional homogeneity across the different water projects and congruence with the design principles is not necessarily a positive factor. Strong differences in household water flows within and among the projects point to the disconnection between apparently successful institutions and their objectives, such as fair and equitable water allocation.

Introduction

In 2002, Kenya undertook a water policy reform that drastically reshaped its institutional arrangements, incorporated in the 2002 Water Act (Government of Kenya 2002) and translated into a recognized legal model for river basin governance. An early success of this reform was the mitigation, and in many cases resolution, of conflicts between upstream and downstream users (Baldwin et al 2015).

The reform was driven by 2 main factors: the difficulty and expense of operating and monitoring the centralized pre-2002 system, which manifested the symptoms of a centralized “prediction and control regime” (Pahl-Wostl 2007), and the impossibility of, and conflict between, downstream and upstream water users (Aarts and Rutten 2012), occasionally involving damage to infrastructure, violent threats, and physical confrontations.

Kenya developed its new river basin governance system in a participatory manner. The inclusion of water experts, nongovernmental organizations, and community representatives in the drafting of the 2002 Water Act produced an institutional architecture that is consistent with recommendations in the literature for creating sustainable governance systems. However, some authors point to critical problems with the act, such as the exclusion of rural poor people, pastoralists, and other marginalized actors from its benefits (Mumma 2005; Robinson et al 2010).

Mount Kenya communities face 2 challenges to the “institutional fit” (Young 2002) of the Water Act reform and to the success of this or any water governance system: rapid population growth and hydroclimatic change. In our area of study, the upper Ewaso Ng’iro River basin, the population increased from 50,000 in 1960 to 500,000 in 2000 (Ngigi et al 2007), and population growth has continued since then. Daily records for Laikipia County show a decline in rainfall frequency and an increase in rainfall magnitude over the last half century (Franz et al 2010); total rainfall in central Kenya is predicted to decrease while average temperatures increase (USGS 2010). Taken together, these trends have important implications for regional water governance through their effect on irrigation demand and river flow. This scenario is problematic for water projects lacking adequate storage facilities, because river water will be less available when it is needed most, during the dry intervals between storms. The challenge posed by these 2 trends—increased irrigation demand and lower water availability during high-demand periods—is heightened by a third element, the challenge of equitably distributing water resources. This is particularly the case in the study area, given that historically, perceptions of water inequality and injustice on Mount Kenya have engendered conflict and violence.

The complex social landscape of Mount Kenya makes water governance a particularly sensitive issue. Perceived water inequality is a serious threat to the governing systems in the region that can affect multiple dimensions of water use. There are water availability and allocation differences between upstream and downstream users, different kinds of users (eg large-scale commercial farms and smallholder farmers), different community water projects (CWPs), and different households in the same CWP. This is problematic, as inter- and intragroup inequalities are consistently correlated with negative outcomes in common-pool resource governance (Andersson and Agrawal 2011). Unequal access to natural resources in sub-Saharan Africa, in particular land and water, is associated with conflicts among different pastoralist tribes as well as between different categories of users and river basin tensions between upstream and downstream groups (Derman et al 2007).

In a context like this, institutional adaptation is particularly important. However, resource governance regimes evolve over time and, among other factors, are strongly affected by the development and state of technological infrastructure, which often leads to technological lock-in (Pahl-Wostl 2009). A similar problem is the phenomenon of institutional lock-in (ie institutional arrangements do not adapt to changing situations because of a series of factors), wherein institutional regimes lose their fit.

Although river water governance takes place at multiple levels, a particularly important level at which to analyze resource management dynamics is the CWP because it represents the organizational structure where water is managed by multiple users through common property regimes. This paper explores CWP-related institutional and management issues with a focus on 5 CWPs in the Likii Water Resource Users Association (WRUA). It analyzes both institutional dynamics and household water flows using Ostrom’s (1990) design principles for natural resource management as a diagnostic framework to investigate CWPs’ governance outcomes with a particular focus on water allocation inequality.

Study area

The study area discussed in this paper coincides with the Likii River WRUA. This area includes 1 of the tributaries of the upper Ewaso Ng’iro River basin, which extends from the northwest foothills of Mount Kenya (Figure 1) to the semiarid Laikipia plateau and the arid northern lowlands and is characterized by strong biophysical and social gradients. Annual mean precipitation ranges from more than 1000 mm at higher elevations to about 475 mm at lower elevations < 100 km away (Notter et al 2007). This precipitation gradient parallels a strong land-use and social gradient from upstream intensive commercial agriculture and smallholder farms to downstream pastoralism. The area’s ethnic composition is also heterogeneous, with predominantly traditional agriculturalist groups such as Meru and Kikuyus engaged in smallholder farming in the upper and middle areas, white Kenyans and European investors operating large-scale commercial farms growing flowers and cash crops for export, and agropastoralist groups such as Maasai and Samburu in the lower areas. Likii WRUA is composed of 9 CWPs, 2 large-scale commercial farms, 1 wildlife conservancy, and the Nanyuki Water and Sewerage Company. The 5 CWPs included in this study are members of the Likii WRUA (Figure 2).

FIGURE 1 

On the way to Mount Kenya. (Photo by Jampel Dell’Angelo)

i0276-4741-36-1-102-f01.tif

FIGURE 2 

Location of CWPs investigated during the study. (Map by Paul McCord)

i0276-4741-36-1-102-f02.tif

CWPs are groups of smallholder households connected to a pipe network providing water for domestic use and irrigation. Smallholder households in the investigated CWPs primarily cultivate maize, potatoes, and beans for subsistence and for local markets. Typically, household field sizes in the study area range between 0.4 and 1.2 ha (McCord et al 2015). Membership in a water project is usually obtained by paying a 1-time membership fee to contribute to the expense of building the piped water network and a monthly fee to support its maintenance. CWPs are composed of a varying number of households and have an elected management committee in charge of the governance and allocation of water resources within the community. CWP boundaries do not always perfectly match those of other administrative units; therefore, it is possible for a CWP to cover only part of a village or other administrative area.

Theoretical background

Scholars of natural resource management have found a correlation between success and longevity of common-pool resource systems, such as community-based irrigation systems, and a set of institutional characteristics. Ostrom (1990) identified 8 “design principles” characterizing best practices and describing rules and structures of robust institutions associated with sustainable governance of common-pool resources. These 8 design principles relate to the boundaries of the system; congruence with local conditions; opportunities for collective choice and local self-determination; approaches to monitoring, sanctions, and conflict resolution; and incorporation of multiple, nested layers of organization. Cox et al (2010), using a probabilistic rather than deterministic approach, found good empirical support for Ostrom’s principles as a diagnostic baseline to understand outcomes resulting from biophysical and social interactions in the management of common-pool resources. Wade (1988) and Baland and Platteau (1996) recognized a set of similar principles.

With regard to community-based irrigation systems, a number of authors have argued that a shift from centralized to decentralized, participatory, community-based systems is desirable (Coward 1979; Wade 1988; Ostrom 1992; Lam 1998). Decentralized community-based systems operate on multiple levels of governance in collaboration and reciprocal recognition (Geertz 1959; Coward 1977, 1979; Siy 1982; Ostrom 1992; Cox 2014). Moreover, there is evidence that the size of the group affects the outcome of irrigation management. Small and medium-sized groups, having fewer transaction costs and stronger reputation-building mechanisms and being directly involved and affected, are generally more functional and adaptive to changing conditions than large schemes (Ostrom et al 1994; Araral 2009).

A high degree of adaptability is required to navigate and govern the rapid socioecological transformations that characterize rural areas affected by hydroclimatic change such as those in the semiarid tropics. The capacity of a system to cope with change without losing future options (Folke et al 2005) is strongly challenged when multiple socioecological stressors coexist. In particular, in order to account for the complexity of water systems on multiple levels and to facilitate rapid changes to cope with the uncertainty that characterizes this complexity, riverine governance should move from technical to flexible and adaptive management (Pahl-Wostl 2007). Adaptive river basin governance has the main features of complex adaptive systems, that is, a high degree of self-organization and distributed control. The adaptive dynamics of water governance systems are determined both by the allocation of water and by the requirements of different actors (Pahl-Wostl 2007). Different actors, often with diverging or conflicting perspectives, negotiate the definition of social priorities in river basin governance.

A successful adaptive system should be based on an active process of social learning characterized by reflexivity, involvement, and participation of actors at multiple scales. Institutional design often prevents systems from adapting and from experimenting with new solutions (Pahl-Wostl 2002). In such situations, which could be characterized as experiencing institutional lock-in, collective learning represents an option for improving management procedures and increasing adaptive capacity.

In systems with a multitude of actors, such as river basin governance, there is a high probability that conflicts rather than collective learning will heavily influence institution building, and conflict can undermine the potential for collective action (Van Laerhoven and Andersson 2013). In relation to water management, there is empirical evidence that unequal access to water resources in situations of scarcity leads to tensions and conflicts (Liniger et al 2005).

Water governance in mountains has social and biophysical features that result in particular institutional challenges (see Mountain Research and Development 2013). However, despite the acknowledged importance of mountain systems as water resource bases, the role of water governance in mountainous areas remains relatively underinvestigated (Molden et al 2013).

Methods

This paper is based on a multimethod approach to socioecological water systems analysis. A team of eco-hydrologists and social scientists designed a protocol of biophysical and social data collection that took place during June–December 2013. Throughout the process, the active participation of local stakeholders was critical. The results presented here, which formed part of a larger fieldwork effort that included 5 river basins, are limited to the Likii River basin and the Likii WRUA. We focused on CWPs that were active members of the Likii WRUA. The 5 CWPs presented here represent different upper-stream and downstream portions of the Likii River. In each CWP, 30 households were selected for semistructured interviews. We also interviewed members of every CWP management committee. The manager interviews and questionnaires addressed general socioeconomic conditions in the CWP’s jurisdiction as well as specific aspects of institutional structure and function, such as composition and management committees, rules and agreements, monitoring and sanctioning approaches, and water rotation schedules.

The biophysical data gathered included water project mapping and water flow measurements. We mapped distribution pipes—using a Hemisphere XF101 Differential Global Positioning System (GPS) receiver (~2 m accuracy) and a Garmin Oregon 400t GPS receiver (~10 m accuracy)—from a vehicle and, in less accessible areas, by foot. The collaboration of CWP piped network caretakers was particularly important in this mapping, as they guided members of the research project and provided information on the size of the pipes, number of users, and rotation schedules. The project selected a purposive sample of households in each of the 5 water projects in order to take water measurements over a 6-month period. Households were selected from the beginning, middle, and end of the water project pipeline. We determined the optimal point for measurement and monitored 10–19 households in each CWP for a 6-month period starting in July 2013. The location of every measurement point was marked with a GPS receiver and added to a geographic information system, where it could be overlaid with additional spatial data. Household flows were measured by using a stopwatch to time the filling of an 18-L bucket. We trained local stakeholders to conduct this measurement consistently across the different water projects.

Results

CWP management and Ostrom’s design principles

Institutions, defined as “enduring regularities of human action in situations structured by rules, norms, and shared strategies, as well as by the physical world” (Crawford and Ostrom 1995: 582), are fundamental determinants of the sustainability of social–ecological systems. Wade (1988), Ostrom (1990), and Baland and Platteau (1996) have laid the foundations for the analysis of sustainable governance of common-pool resources. With their comparative studies they have investigated what institutional features are likely to be associated with sustainable collective use of natural resources. In particular, Elinor Ostrom, based on extensive studies of long-enduring governing institutions of common-pool resources, identified 8 “design principles” (Table 1) that synthesize the institutional regularities of sustainable natural resource management across different systems such as fisheries, forests, and community irrigation projects (Ostrom 1990, 2009; Anderies et al 2004).

TABLE 1 

Ostrom’s 8 design principles for natural resource management of common-pool resources.

i0276-4741-36-1-102-t01.tif

The interpretation of these principles in the literature on natural resource management has been diverse. Some scholars have understood them as a normative blueprint, whereas others have focused on their heuristic or diagnostic potential. This paper, in line with Cox et al (2010), uses the 8 design principles to study the similarities and differences in institutional arrangements across different CWPs in the same WRUA. In other words, we do not assess the institutional performance of the projects based on the correspondence between their management rules and the principles, but we use the principles to compare and analyze their institutional characteristics.

The data gathered from interviews with executive members of the CWP management committees show that their institutional structures generally reflect the 8 design principles. This correspondence is summarized in Tables 2 and 3 and discussed in more detail below.

TABLE 2 

Survey results in relation to Ostrom’s design principles 1–4.

i0276-4741-36-1-102-t02.tif

TABLE 3 

Survey results in relation to Ostrom’s design principles 5–8.

i0276-4741-36-1-102-t03.tif

Principle 1: Clear boundaries

This principle refers to the need to define both the physical extent of the resource and the group of individuals with the right to use the resource (Cox et al 2010). The CWPs investigated for this study have clear criteria that potential users must meet before they can qualify for membership and the right to withdraw water. The main criteria for membership are payment of membership fees, payment of monthly fees, and land ownership in the area covered by the piped network. Two CWPs also require permission from the management committee and the contribution of labor and time. At the CWP level, there are clearly identified resource boundaries. However, at the river-basin level, all of the CWPs draw from the same general source and need to create higher-level technical and institutional boundaries. This is the level of governance where the WRUA has the authority to define the boundaries. WRUA management committees, on which all WRUA members are represented, agree on water allocation using rotation schedules and different diameters of intake pipes for different members according to their typology and characteristics (eg population size of the CWP).

Principle 2: Congruence with local conditions

This principle requires that rules concerning the time, place, method, and amount of resource extraction must be appropriate to local conditions (Cox et al 2010). It relates to the concept of fit between a set of institutions and an environment or ecosystem (Ekstrom and Young 2009). We investigated how water is distributed and how the system changes during droughts. In irrigation systems, this is a good measure of how institutions reflect local biophysical patterns. All of the CWPs in the study allocate water on a rotating basis, and 4 of the 5 allot water access for specific units of time. All adjust water allocation in response to scarcity. The rationing and rotation procedures are negotiated in a participative way and not imposed by an external authority. This increases the congruence between the rules and strategies adopted and local social and biophysical conditions.

Principle 3: Collective-choice arrangements

Under this principle, resource users impacted by operational rules can participate in modifying those rules (Cox et al 2010). In-depth interviews with CWP management committee members and WRUA executive members, and review of bylaws and other documentation, revealed that bottom-up representation is a fundamental feature of the Likii subcatchment governance (see Dell’Angelo et al 2014). Every CWP elects the management committee executive members and the chair of the committee, who then represents the CWP on the WRUA management committee, which is the main legislative body. This provides a system and procedure by which the people affected by the rules can participate in setting or modifying them. Our interviews inquired about the CWPs’ ability to enter into agreements with other communities within the WRUA regarding water extraction from the Likii River, which shows the level of institutional coordination across different projects.

Principle 4: Monitoring

This principle requires that users’ behavior is monitored, and that the monitors either are accountable to the users or are themselves users (Cox et al 2010). Effective monitoring takes place at the CWP level, where the management committee members and caretakers of the project are able to verify the correct functioning and water use. The sampled CWPs have clear monitoring regimes, including the use of headgate gauges to monitor community-level appropriation as well as monitoring of individual users by the CWP management committee members. Some CWPs also reported that community members actively engaged in monitoring.

Monitoring is also a central aspect of WRUA governance. Monitoring is implemented by the WRUA’s technical officer and personnel, but there are strong limitations to its effectiveness for several reasons, including lack of personnel, the size of the area that needs to be monitored, and the frequency of unregulated water abstraction. For this reason, although the WRUA has established a rotation system for water allocation that should ideally determine the amount of water abstracted from the river, the lack of monitoring capacity at the river-basin level makes it challenging to enforce these water use limits at the river-basin level.

Principle 5: Graduated sanctions

Under this principle, the severity of sanctions depends on the character or frequency of violations of community rules. This deters repeat violations while maintaining community cohesion by avoiding disproportionate sanctions for minor rule violations (Cox et al 2010). Scholars debate whether sanctions are necessary in communities with strong social capital, and some have argued that they cannot be a replacement for it (Cleaver 2000). However, CWP committee members interviewed for this study said that sanctions are a useful tool. The CWPs investigated for this study generally impose moderate penalties (such as loss of water) for minor rule violations (such as failure to pay monthly fees or to contribute labor). Of the 5 CWPs, 4 had clearly articulated penalties associated with illegal pumping or tampering with the pipe system. Repeat violations, or more serious violations such as illegal pumping or pipe tampering, can lead to financial penalties or loss of CWP membership.

Principle 6: Conflict-resolution mechanisms

The upper Ewaso Ng’iro River subcatchment has been strongly affected by conflicts between users, both between downstream and upstream users and among smallholders in the same areas. Study participants reported that participation in the CWPs prevented conflict between users regarding water access, and participants from 4 of the 5 CWPs reported that they had previously received complaints from users about water access. Communities are also able to turn to the WRUA and the Water Resource Management Authority (WRMA) to resolve intercommunity disputes.

This is consistent with the findings of other studies that the implementation of the WRUA system in 2002 has been an effective solution to many of these conflicts (Liniger et al 2005; Baldwin et al 2015). A fundamental feature of the WRUA is its basis in democratic representation and deliberation. It has also provided the more disadvantaged users (those living downstream) a forum in which to express their concerns. The WRUA has also increased transparency and information on water availability and use.

Principle 7: Recognition of the right to organization

Recognition by external government agencies of a community’s right to self-organize allows the community to establish rules that are appropriate for local conditions. Conversely, where external government agencies do not recognize a community’s right to self-organize and instead impose externally generated rules, those rules may not correspond with local conditions and may lead to undesired governance outcomes (Cox et al 2010). The WRUA architecture is based on the principle of involving the communities in the governance system and recognizing their right to manage the resource. This happens through a bottom-up representation system that begins with the election of the CWP representatives. The CWPs are constitutive components of the WRUAs, recognized by the WRMA and by the Ministry of Water and Irrigation, and their role is emphasized in the national legislation.

Principle 8: Nested governance

According to Ostrom (1990), governance activities that are organized in “multiple layers of nested enterprises” are more likely to be associated with successful outcomes. The Likii WRUA shows clear characteristics of nested governance, with decision-making taking place at multiple levels. Decisions at the CWP level are made by a management committee democratically elected by community members. The chairs of the management committees constitute the WRUA management committee, and the WRUA receives instructions from WRMA and the Ministry of Water and Irrigation. The general relationship between the different decision levels is not strictly hierarchical, but it works through feedback and mutual influence.

Demographic pressure and water management implications

The chairs of several CWPs stated that membership had greatly increased in the past 5 years. The secretary of one CWP stated that “the increase in population has led to more people irrigating.” This CWP has capped membership so that no new individuals can join, in order to allow existing members to maintain their livelihood practices (including irrigation) even as the population of surrounding areas increases. The secretary of another CWP stated that the project’s management committee had recently decided to cap its membership because there was not enough water. He attributed this partly to the growth of the project’s membership from 279 members in ~2008 to 366 in 2013. Another CWP’s caretaker stated that it has only been within the past 5 years that the water project has been forced to implement a rotation schedule during dry periods, because of an increase in membership (fueled by an increase in population in the surrounding area). One CWP chairman stated that the management committee has intentionally kept membership numbers low so that water does not become too scarce.

Household water flow differences

In parallel with the institutional analysis, we measured household water flow rates for 6 months across the 5 water projects. In terms of average household flow rate for each CWP as a whole, the projects fell roughly into 2 groups. There were only slight differences between CWPs 1, 2, and 3, but there was a strong difference between this group and the other 2 CWPs, which had much lower average rates (Table 4).

TABLE 4 

Average household flow rates (L/min): differences between CWPs.

i0276-4741-36-1-102-t04.tif

Between households within a single CWP, flow rate differences varied, in some cases substantially. This shows a fundamental challenge of community water governance. CWP bylaws mandate equitable allocation of water to all member households. However, substantial differences existed for each CWP between the highest and lowest household flow rates. In CWPs 1, 3, and 4, the maximum flow was about twice the minimum flow; in CWPs 2 and 5, the maximum was almost 3 times the minimum (Table 5).

TABLE 5 

Average household flow rates (L/min): differences within CWPs.

i0276-4741-36-1-102-t05.tif

We also mapped the CWP pipe networks along with average household flow measurements to show the spatial distribution of household-level flow rates (Figures 3, 4). These maps suggest that some potential explanations for differences in flow rate can likely be ruled out, including the specific position on the lines and distance from the CWP intake.

FIGURE 3 

Pipe network and sampled households, CWP 1. (Map by Paul McCord)

i0276-4741-36-1-102-f03.tif

FIGURE 4 

Pipe network and sampled households, CWP 2. (Map by Paul McCord)

i0276-4741-36-1-102-f04.tif

Discussion and conclusions

Kenya’s 2002 water reform established institutions that adopt many widely accepted governance best practices, such as involving local stakeholders, encouraging active participation, building capacity, devolving centralized powers to local actors, and allocating water equitably. The governance system in the upper Ewaso Ng’iro River basin of Mount Kenya has been described as an example of this positive institutional transformation (Baldwin et al 2015). The research presented in this paper explored the institutional and biophysical dynamics of water governance at the CWP level through the lens of Ostrom’s (1990) 8 design principles of natural-resource management.

We found a degree of institutional homogeneity among the 5 CWPs studied. However, this is not necessarily good news. An important debate on Ostrom’s design principles for common-pool resources management is whether they can be considered a blueprint for sustainable governance (Cox et al 2010). The lack of diversity among the different CWPs might indicate that decentralization and the move to more participatory water governance could have replaced one institutionally locked-in system with another. There is consensus that the current water governance system has produced positive management outcomes, increased dialogue and participation, and decreased conflicts (Liniger et al 2005; Baldwin et al 2015), but the concern is that the current system is not adaptive to changing conditions such as the double threat of hydroclimatic change and population growth.

There are 2 main trends in the CWPs of the Likii WRUA: (1) a certain degree of institutional homogeneity and (2) a high level of inter- and intra-CWP differences in water flow. The origin of these differences is beyond the scope of this paper, but it is important to recognize what they imply and what they signal. The first implication of these results is the discrepancy between the CWPs’ consistency with Ostrom’s design principles and their low level of adaptation to change. From interview and questionnaire responses by executive members of the CWP management committee, it is possible to understand the standardized nature of the procedures, functions, and decisions of these committees. In particular, the role of information, such as the information on household water flows that we report here, is overshadowed by routine management tasks such as collection of fees, monitoring, maintenance, and meetings. Moreover, formal management procedures reveal only 1 side of the story. There is a critical component of decision-making in the CWPs that happens in the management committee and is more influenced by the interaction of individual preferences and group social–psychological dynamics than by formal rules (Dell’Angelo et al 2015). Combining institutional analysis with the social psychology of group dynamics is a particularly important direction for future research on community-based natural resources governance.

The second implication is that lack of information combined with inequalities in water flow has been historically associated with conflicts and tensions (Liniger et al 2005). This paper, which focuses on the CWPs, shows only 1 of the many dimensions of water inequality that characterize the upper Ewaso Ng’iro River basin. Even more striking inequalities exist between CWP members, who can afford to pay for membership and water access, and nonmember households, which are often trapped in a vicious cycle of lack of economic assets leading to lack of the water necessary to develop economic assets. Similar water inequalities occur between downstream and upstream users and between different categories of users (eg commercial farms, smallholder farmers, and pastoralists). Moreover, CWP-level consistency with Ostrom’s design principles does not imply the same for the (higher) WRUA level of governance. Investigation of the institutional dynamics of the WRUA is also necessary to assess overall river basin governance.

Inter- and intra-CWP water differences point to the existence of several dynamics that can threaten the sustainability of a socioecological system and its governance structures. Even systems with positive features such those identified by Ostrom’s 8 design principles may not be able to keep up with changes in socioecological conditions. Adaptive governance is challenging, and the speed and scope of change requires an intense and constant involvement of stakeholders and redefinition of institutional strategies. The future of Mount Kenya’s water governance will largely depend on how the different actors are able to collaborate and share information and on how responsive to socioenvironmental change the institutional adaptations are.

Open access article: please credit the authors and the full source.

Acknowledgements

We gratefully acknowledge support from the US National Science Foundation (grants BCS—1115009, SES—1360463 and DBI—1052875 to SESYNC). We are very thankful to the anonymous reviewers who helped us improve the manuscript with fruitful comments. Special thanks to the farmers and community water scheme member and managers who supported us throughout the project. Thank you to Daniel Yuan Cheng for his collaboration. We thank Anne Zimmermann and Amanda Morgan for their precious editorial support.

References

1.

J Aarts M. Rutten 2012. Will community based water management solve Africa’s water problems? The performance of water user associations in the Upper Ewaso Ng’iro River basin, Kenya. Presented at the Embattled Spaces—Contested Orders Conference, VAD Association for African Studies in Germany. Cologne, Germany, 30 May–2 June.  https://cmsdata.iucn.org/downloads/aartsvadewasonn.pdf; accessed on 28 December 2015. Google Scholar

2.

JM Anderies MA Janssen E. Ostrom 2004. A framework to analyze the robustness of social-ecological systems from an institutional perspective. Ecology and Society 9(1):18. Google Scholar

3.

K Andersson A. Agrawal 2011. Inequalities, institutions, and forest commons. Global Environmental Change 21(3):866–875.  http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2011.03.004Google Scholar

4.

E. Araral 2009. What explains collective action in the commons? Theory and evidence from the Philippines. World Development 37(3):687–697. Google Scholar

5.

JM Baland JP. Platteau 1996. Halting Degradation of Natural Resources: Is There a Role for Rural Communities. ? Rome, Italy: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. Google Scholar

6.

E Baldwin C Washington-Ottombre J Dell’Angelo D Cole TP. Evans 2015. Polycentric governance and irrigation reform in Kenya. Governance, Early View, 14 August 2015.  http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/gove.12160Google Scholar

7.

F. Cleaver 2000. Moral ecological rationality, institutions and the management of common property resources. Development and Change 31(2):361–383. Google Scholar

8.

EW. Coward 1977. Irrigation management alternatives: Themes from indigenous irrigation systems. Agricultural Administration 4(3):223–237. Google Scholar

9.

EW Jr. Coward 1979. Principles of social organization in an indigenous irrigation system. Human Organization 38(1):28–36. Google Scholar

10.

M. Cox 2014. Applying a social-ecological system framework to the study of the Taos valley irrigation system. Human Ecology 42(2):311–324. Google Scholar

11.

M Cox G Arnold S. Villamayor-Tomás 2010. A review of design principles for community-based natural resource management. Ecology & Society 15(4):1–19. Google Scholar

12.

SE Crawford E. Ostrom 1995. A grammar of institutions. American Political Science Review 89(3):582–600.  http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2082975Google Scholar

13.

J Dell’Angelo P McCord E Baldwin M Cox D Gower K Caylor T. Evans 2014. Multi-level governance of irrigation systems and adaptation to climate change in Kenya. In: J Bogardi A Bhaduri J Leentvaar S Marx editors. The Global Water System in the Anthropocene. New York, NY: Springer, pp 323–341. Google Scholar

14.

J Dell’Angelo P McCord C Muriuki T. Evans 2015. Who decides? Investigating decision making dynamics of community water projects on Mount Kenya. Unpublished paper presented at the Fifteenth Biennial Conference of the International Association for the Study of the Commons. Edmonton, Alberta, 25–29 May. Available from corresponding author of this article. Google Scholar

15.

B Derman R Odgaard E. Sjaastad 2007. Conflicts Over Land and Water in Africa. London, United Kingdom: James Currey. Google Scholar

16.

JA Ekstrom OR. Young 2009. Evaluating functional fit between a set of institutions and an ecosystem. Ecology & Society 14(2):1–18. Google Scholar

17.

C Folke T Hahn P Olsson J. Norberg 2005 Adaptive governance of social-ecological systems. Annual Review of Environment and Resources 30:441–473. Google Scholar

18.

T Franz K Caylor J Nordbotten I Rodríguez-Iturbe M. Celia 2010. An ecohydrological approach to predicting regional woody species distribution pattern in dryland ecosystems. Advances in Water Resources 33:215–230. Google Scholar

19.

C. Geertz 1959. Form and variation in Balinese village structure. American Anthropologist 61:991–1012. Google Scholar

20.

Government of Kenya. 2002. The water act. Republic of Kenya 2002. The Water Act. Nairobi, Kenya. Government Printers.. Google Scholar

21.

WF. Lam 1998. Governing Irrigation Systems in Nepal: Institutions, Infrastructure, and Collective Action. Oakland, CA: ICS Press. Google Scholar

22.

H Liniger J Gikonyo B Kiteme U. Wiesmann 2005 Assessing and managing scarce tropical mountain water resources: The case of Mount Kenya and the semiarid Upper Ewaso Ng’iro basin. Mountain Research and Development 25(2):163–173. Google Scholar

23.

PF McCord M Cox M Schmitt-Harsh T. Evans 2015. Crop diversification as a smallholder livelihood strategy within semi-arid agricultural systems near Mount Kenya. Land Use Policy 42:738–750. Google Scholar

24.

DH Molden H Hurni A Zimmermann S. Wymann von Dach 2013. Focus issue: Water governance in mountains [editorial]. Mountain Research and Development 33(3):193–194. Google Scholar

25.

Mountain Research and Development. 2013. Focus issue: water governance in mountains. Mountain Research and Development 33(3):192–359. Google Scholar

26.

A. Mumma 2005. Kenya’s new water law: An analysis of the implications for the rural poor. Presented at African Water Laws: Plural Legislative Frameworks for Rural Water Management in Africa. Johannesburg, South Africa, January 26–28.  http://projects.nri.org/waterlaw/AWLworkshop/MUMMA-A.pdf; accessed on 24 March 2016. Google Scholar

27.

SN Ngigi HHG Savenije FN. Gichuki 2007. Land use changes and hydrological impacts related to up-scaling of rainwater harvesting and management in upper Ewaso Ng’iro river basin, Kenya. Land Use Policy 24:129–140. Google Scholar

28.

B Notter L MacMillan D Viviroli R Weingartner HP. Liniger 2007. Impacts of environmental change on water resources in the Mt. Kenya region. Journal of Hydrology 343(3–4): 266–278.  http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jhydrol.2007.06.022Google Scholar

29.

E. Ostrom 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge, MA. Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar

30.

E. Ostrom 1992. Crafting Institutions for Self-Governing Irrigation Systems. Oakland, CA: ICS [Institute for Contemporary Studies] Press. Google Scholar

31.

E. Ostrom 2009. A general framework for analyzing sustainability of socialecological systems. Science 325(5939): 419–422. Google Scholar

32.

E Ostrom R Gardner J. Walker 1994. Rules, Games, and Common-Pool Resources. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Google Scholar

33.

C. Pahl-Wostl 2002. Towards sustainability in the water sector: The importance of human actors and processes of social learning. Aquatic Sciences 64(4):394–411.  http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/PL00012594Google Scholar

34.

C. Pahl-Wostl 2007. Transitions towards adaptive management of water facing climate and global change. Water Resources Management 21(1):49–62.  http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11269-006-9040-4Google Scholar

35.

C. Pahl-Wostl 2009. A conceptual framework for analysing adaptive capacity and multi-level learning processes in resource governance regimes. Global Environmental Change 19(3):354–365.  http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2009.06.001Google Scholar

36.

LW Robinson JA Sinclair H. Spaling 2010. Traditional pastoralist decision-making processes: Lessons for reforms to water resources management in Kenya. Journal of Environmental Planning and Management 53(7):847–862. Google Scholar

37.

RY. Siy 1982. Community Resource Management: Lessons from the Zanjera. Quezon City, Philippines: University of Philippines Press. Google Scholar

38.

USGS [United States Geological Survey]. 2010. A Climate Trend Analysis of Kenya—August 2010. Famine Early Warning Systems Network Informing Climate Change Adaptation Series. USGS: Available online at:   http://pubs.usgs.gov/fs/2010/3074/pdf/fs2010-3074.pdfGoogle Scholar

39.

F van Laerhoven KP. Andersson 2013. The virtue of conflict: An institutional approach to the study of conflict in community forest governance. International Forestry Review 15(1):122–135.  http://dx.doi.org/10.1505/146554813805927219Google Scholar

40.

R. Wade 1988. Village Republics: Economic Conditions for Collective Action in South India. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar

41.

OR. Young 2002. The Institutional Dimensions of Environmental Change: Fit, Interplay, and Scale. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Google Scholar
International Mountain Society
Jampel Dell’Angelo, Paul F. McCord, Drew Gower, Stefan Carpenter, Kelly K. Caylor, and Tom P. Evans "Community Water Governance on Mount Kenya: An Assessment Based on Ostrom’s Design Principles of Natural Resource Management," Mountain Research and Development 36(1), 102-115, (1 February 2016). https://doi.org/10.1659/MRD-JOURNAL-D-15-00040.1
Received: 1 October 2015; Accepted: 1 December 2015; Published: 1 February 2016
KEYWORDS
community-based water management
household water flow
institutional fit
Kenya water reform
Mountain water governance
Ostrom’s 8 design principles
Back to Top